|
Turkey
Economy: Gauging the Size of Turkey's Informal Sector
The informal sector, ranging from illicit trade to
organised crime, plays a major role in Turkey's
economic life. It has both pernicious and benign
aspects
Hawkers displaying plastic toys or T-shirts, elbow-to-elbow
on crowded shopping streets; home-workers stitching
up shirts for textiles factories; repair jobs and
domestic cleaning done for cash without receipt-all
these are just the tip of the iceberg of Turkey's large unreported economy. As much as 70% of milk and
meat is sold outside formal channels, and software
piracy recently fell to "only" 58%. Manufacturers,
traders and professionals commonly straddle the
notional dividing line between the visible and
invisible sectors, under-reporting their turnovers
for tax purposes. Services and supplies are
regularly outsourced to "grey-area" suppliers, and
double accounting and "nylon" (false) receipts are
commonplace. In 2003 US$4bn worth of goods of
unspecified origin was exported to former communist
countries under the guise of "suitcase trade",
according to possibly conservative Central Bank of
Turkey estimates. Meanwhile, a wide range of
foodstuffs and cheap manufactured goods make their
way into Turkey equally unrecorded. Smuggled watches
are said to account for 80% of the market and
contraband mobile telephones for 20-25%. In eastern
provinces, livestock smuggling is a way of life, and
agriculture officials attempting to register cattle
have met with stiff local resistance.
No tax please
In employment, informality is rampant. Official
household labour-force survey results for the second
quarter of 2004 indicate that no social security
contributions were paid for 90% of day-labourers or
for over one-quarter of regular private sector
employees-some 3.6m people in all. From the point of
view of tax, the situation is little different.
Investigations into income tax declarations
regularly reveal that up to twice as much income has
been disguised as declared. In these circumstances,
the social security institutions require heavy
subsidies, public services are underfunded and
honest employers and taxpayers are penalised.
Over 70% of tax revenue has come to be derived from
indirect taxes, particularly those paid by "captive
audiences" such as vehicle-owners, drinkers, smokers
and telephone subscribers. Even this is only a
partial solution: smuggled, imitation cigarettes are
openly and widely sold, and Yusuf Gunay, the head of
the Energy Market Regulation Authority, estimates
that US$2bn-4bn is being lost each year in tax
revenue as a result of the smuggling of fuels from
neighbouring countries. A vicious circle of high tax
rates and high tax avoidance has set in. Unfair
competition is rife, markets are distorted and
formal investment is discouraged.
Besides the desire to evade taxes and bureaucracy,
the size of the unreported economy reflects the
failure of the state and private investors to create
formal jobs for a growing population and the
existence of millions of small firms and micro-businesses.
As often as not, politicians have treated these
informal enterprises-like illegal housing and
property occupations-as a kind of social safety net,
if not as a source of votes and even party funding.
Tax laws are riddled with exemptions, and
declarations of wealth have repeatedly been rejected
as an intrusion on personal life and a disincentive
to economic activity. Governments have consistently
failed to enforce laws on tax, social security,
capital markets and so on.
Reporting the unreported
Economists have attempted to calculate the amount of
economic activity that fails to show up in the
national income figures. It is a thankless task.
There is no flawless method, and no perfect
definition-should one include, for example, non-commercial
household production, or the plentiful income
obtained from illegal acts such as drug-running,
mafia operations and Internet gambling? Most
calculations of the size of the unreported economy
fall short of the intuitive oft-quoted figure of 50%
of official GDP.
In a World Bank-sponsored paper in 2002, Friedrich
Schneider adopted a figure of 31.2% for 2000-relatively
high by the standards of Europe and Asia, but only a
few percentage points above Italy, Spain, Greece and
Belgium, and well below many African and Latin
American countries. It has to be remembered that the
official GDP data are themselves based on a series
of estimates, assumptions and cross-checks, and
consequently do not exclude all goods and services
that are untaxed or produced by informal labour. The
new national income series to be published in 2005
can be expected to encompass still more of this
hidden output.
Finally, the relative size of the unreported economy
may ebb and flow with economic cycles, expanding at
times of crisis as formal jobs are lost, as
taxpayers defend their living standards by reporting
less of their income, and as demand collapses in
some of the best-reported sectors such as
automotives or consumer durables. If this is the
case, it would help to explain the depth of the 2001
recession and the rapid official growth rates in
2002-04.
|